Wednesday, May 30, 2012
When all the choices are bad
When the referendum on the Good Friday Agreement was held I flew back from France to vote and if I still had an address in Ireland I'd be doing the same tomorrow. Trouble is I'm not sure what way I'd vote, not because I don't agree with Paul Krugman's cogent arguments for voting against the austerity pact, but because the price Ireland might pay for doing so could be really terrible. It comes down to a political calculation. If an Irish No vote was likely to provoke a crisis in the entire strategy of the European Union it would be worth the risk, but if not the chances are Ireland would be made an example of to illustrate just how dangerous it is to think that you really retain real political agency as a small country in the Union. In the end we probably should do the brave thing and get up on the barricade, but it would be nice if the Belgians or the Luxembourgeois got to be at the point of crisis and not us. It would also be comfortable to be able to persuade myself that the austerity programme is so irrational that it will collapse without any help, and so we could vote safely with a good conscience. But a sad history has confirmed that economic relations do not impose rationality on us and if we don't attend to the political moment on its own terms it just makes matters worse. Once more into the breach....
Sunday, May 20, 2012
The End of (yet another) Illusion
David Brooks had a piece in the New York Times during the week analysing the structural problems in western democracies. The argument derives from Tocqueville's aristocratic liberalism; democracy only works when a well-designed constitution gives directing power to a wise elite who can balance the passions of the multitude, but are themselves constrained by divided government. The passions have been left unconstrained and the elites no longer committed to civic governance so the system is falling apart as elites try to buy power by pandering to the passions rather than controlling them. This position is shared in whole or part by a lot of clever people who developed their thinking in response to the crisis of liberal democracy in the seventies and the closure of one way thinking marked by the "halt of the forward march of labour". In certain corners of the academy and government this kind of thinking is taken very seriously. Tocquevillian liberalism is coherent and one can reconstruct rationally how it became attractive to liberal intellectuals, but it is one more false god that leads us astray. It is of no use at all when trying to imagine a way through the present crisis in a way that could sustain and enhance the fabric of a free society.
A blog post is to short to develop a full critique of aristocratic liberalism and all I want to do is point out that is a bad guide to history and so likely to be a bad guide in politics. In really major structural crises free societies have not relied on the conservatism of Toqueville but the moral force of Jacobinism. Lincoln and Roosevelt both faced existential threats to the survival of the republic and appealed to justice and the people to mobilise its defense. Both faced real opposition from the bastion of restraint, the supreme court. It was their capacity to define a compelling account of justice and freedom, not their capacity to manipulate the elements of the system that made them successful. It might be worth looking at Roosevelt's four freedoms again too.
A blog post is to short to develop a full critique of aristocratic liberalism and all I want to do is point out that is a bad guide to history and so likely to be a bad guide in politics. In really major structural crises free societies have not relied on the conservatism of Toqueville but the moral force of Jacobinism. Lincoln and Roosevelt both faced existential threats to the survival of the republic and appealed to justice and the people to mobilise its defense. Both faced real opposition from the bastion of restraint, the supreme court. It was their capacity to define a compelling account of justice and freedom, not their capacity to manipulate the elements of the system that made them successful. It might be worth looking at Roosevelt's four freedoms again too.
Friday, May 11, 2012
John Dunn's History of Democracy and the Crisis
In his brilliant book on Democracy John Dunn offers a gloomy prognosis for the fate of representative democracy in economic depression. For Dunn Madisonian representative democracy carries off the amazing trick of uniting political equality with the growth of "opulence and distinctions" but "could scarcely work for long anywhere where distinction must be sustained through stagnant or diminishing wealth, and has been widely and understandably abandoned, often with little hesitation, in circumstances of this kind" (128). In such crises, such as the one we are now suffering, various exits and options become attractive. The option that captures most of Dunn's attention is the antithesis to Madisonian representative democracy. Egalitarian democracy, whose origin is found in Babeuf's response to Thermidor, aims to eliminate opulence and distinctions. Dunn's reflections on the prospects for democracy are carried out in the space between these two poles.
There is logically a third option, a democracy that proposes opulence but is hostile to distinctions (there is also a modern regime that is hostile to opulence and seeks distinctions but I cannot imagine any way to call such a regime democratic). That is not just a space on a logical grid but is the ground occupied by both Social Democracy and Christian Democracy. For the purposes of this reflection the many differences between these two political traditions are less important than the strategy they share. Both traditions manage the chaos generated by the growth, or decline, of opulence by insuring the citizen against the loss of access to various public goods, to their capacity to act as a citizen. The term used very often in French public debate as a norm against which public policy can be judged, "inclusion", captures well the trajectory of this mode of thought and governance. Distinctions, which from this ground are understood as privileges, threaten democratic inclusion, opulence is neutral.
I have written at length on the emergence of Social Democracy from the wreckage of Jacobinism, and the relationship between the French Revolution and the possibilities of democracy is a generally well-worked theme, most recently in the work of Pierre Rosanvallon. I don't know of a similar body of work on Christian Democracy. Obviously these traditions don't exhaust the repertoire of the Atlantic political imaginary, but if Dunn is right about Madison's brainchild, then they will have to bear a heavy load in the resolution to our current difficulties.
There is logically a third option, a democracy that proposes opulence but is hostile to distinctions (there is also a modern regime that is hostile to opulence and seeks distinctions but I cannot imagine any way to call such a regime democratic). That is not just a space on a logical grid but is the ground occupied by both Social Democracy and Christian Democracy. For the purposes of this reflection the many differences between these two political traditions are less important than the strategy they share. Both traditions manage the chaos generated by the growth, or decline, of opulence by insuring the citizen against the loss of access to various public goods, to their capacity to act as a citizen. The term used very often in French public debate as a norm against which public policy can be judged, "inclusion", captures well the trajectory of this mode of thought and governance. Distinctions, which from this ground are understood as privileges, threaten democratic inclusion, opulence is neutral.
I have written at length on the emergence of Social Democracy from the wreckage of Jacobinism, and the relationship between the French Revolution and the possibilities of democracy is a generally well-worked theme, most recently in the work of Pierre Rosanvallon. I don't know of a similar body of work on Christian Democracy. Obviously these traditions don't exhaust the repertoire of the Atlantic political imaginary, but if Dunn is right about Madison's brainchild, then they will have to bear a heavy load in the resolution to our current difficulties.
Monday, May 7, 2012
Caleb Garth's Guide to the Crisis
The
French and Greek elections have given a new twist to Europe's path through the
economic crisis. It is very hopeful that democratic structures are giving the
citizenry a means of expressing their rejection of the strategy of
retrenchment, though it is just funny to see in Francois Hollande anybody's
idea of a socialist firebrand. The 7% vote for the Greek neo-fascists is
worrying, as was Le Pen's showing in the first round, but, sadly, it is hardly
surprising that a variety of soft or hard fascist exit is tempting to at least
some European voters. Some sort of Keynesian expansion is more likely this
morning than it was on Saturday, but that is only the beginning of getting us
out of this mess. So far nobody has even begun to imagine what a better and more
stable economic future would look like.
Much
alternative thinking comes down to a rejection of economic modernity. That can
have a pleasing purity to it, but the road to an ecologically balanced bucolic
utopia remains unclear. The more pressing need is to disaggregate contemporary
life to try to find some solid timbers to frame a more robust economic house.
Debt mediated by sophisticated financial instruments has not proved to be a
solid foundation. The humanities can help us to explore latent contents in
our culture and the English novels of the middle nineteenth century are a great
source of thinking about a commercial order. Caleb Garth in Middlemarch is a
particularly useful figure to think with. Garth is an estate agent (not a house seller but a land agent) and improver
who has the most passionate attachment to business but no head for money;
"the echoes of great hammer where roof or keel were a-making, the signal
shouts of the workmen, the roar of the furnace, the thunder and plash of the
engine, were a sublime music to him,..., but he could not manage finance: he
knew values well, but he had no keenness of imagination for monetary results in
the shape of profit and loss". Garth is a font of entrepreneurial energy,
much of it directed to social ends such as his daughter's happiness, and by
contrast the banker, Mr Bulstrode, who has a very clear grasp of profit and
loss, is morally hollow. Garth is a figure from the technical Enlightenment,
the kind of character Larry Stewart, Margaret Jacob and Jeff Horn write about and it is
worthwhile to be reminded that the project of "improvement" and the
project of capitalism were not originally imagined to be the same thing.
Money is supposed to work as a means of
co-ordination. It is supposed to allow new kinds of work, to channel resources
to encourage new ideas to take material form. The criticism of money has always
been that whoever controlled it had monopoly control over every other kind of
activity and its defense that every other kind of co-ordination contained even
more oppressive possibilities. What is new in America and Europe is that the
asset values that give money meaning, since they are what money controls and
deploys, have become so inflated that most work is now directed toward
sustaining existing value, not making new ideas material or finding new patterns
of communication and co-ordination. Money is getting in the way. Inequality is
a terrible problem that wears through the fabric of democratic societies, but
that could be addressed by obvious kinds of tax policy. More insidious is the
implication of a majority in asset values through home ownership and pension
funds. We are trapped in a vicious circle where profit margins are maintained
by cutting labour costs, which drive down wages and lower aggregate demand.
This should be politically impossible, but the electorate are more frightened
of losing the value of their pensions or the capital in their house, than they
are of their income being depressed. And in any case there are winners in this
kind of spiral. Just how to get out this spiral, and reapportion wealth to work
and not money, is the political challenge of the time. Can we imagine a
market-based economy that does not use money as a means of conducting
transactions? Can we make the world safe for Garth and dangerous for Bulstrode?
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)